Habit formation, equilibrium yield curve, and interest rate lower bound¶
Author(s): Kohei Hasui
Work in progress (Aug 2022).
Presented at a joint APIR/JCER seminar on Sep 9, 2022.
Abstract:
This study investigates the impact of habit formation on the equilibrium yield curve in a New Keynesian model incorporating recursive preferences and a zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate. We compare the impact of habit formation in two monetary policy schemes: the Taylor rule and optimal discretionary policy. Numerical results show that habit persistence significantly amplifies the effect of zero interest rates on equilibrium yield and term premium under optimal discretionary policy, but not under the Taylor rule.
Real-world central banks have a strong aversion to policy reversals. Nevertheless, theoretical models of monetary policy within the dynamic general equilibrium framework normally ignore the irreversibility of interest rate control. In this paper, we develop a formal model that incorporates a central bank’s discretionary optimization problem with an aversion to policy reversals. We show that, even under a discretionary regime, the optimal timing of liftoff from the zero lower bound is characterized by its history dependence, which arises from the option value to waiting, and there exists an optimal degree of policy irreversibility at which the social loss is minimized.
This paper investigates a robust monetary policy under speed limit policy when a central bank fears model misspecification. We show that the persistence of the output gap becomes small with the robust speed limit policy. The low persistence of the output gap contributes to mitigating the variance of the output gap. Also, with a robust policy, social losses are lower under the speed limit policy than under precommitment. Our results suggest that adding the growth of the output gap to the central bank’s objectives is effective when the worst-case scenario is realized.
Recent monetary policy studies have shown that the trend productivity growth has non-trivial implications for monetary policy. This paper investigates how trend growth alters the effect of model uncertainty on macroeconomic fluctuations by introducing a robust control problem. We show that an increase in trend growth reduces the effect of the central bank’s model uncertainty and, hence, mitigates the large macroeconomic fluctuations. Moreover, the increase in trend growth contributes to bringing the economy into determinacy regions even if larger model uncertainty exists. These results indicate that trend growth contributes to stabilizing the economy in terms of both variance and determinacy when model uncertainty exists.
Proposition 2.In the worst-case scenario, a higher trend growth decreases the effect of the central bank’s model uncertainty on the inflation rate, the output gap, and the policy rate under Assumptions 1 and 2.
Proof. […] Combining these conditions, we determine the signs of the cross-derivative as follows: [6]
Since \(\sigma >1\), the signs of inequalities are negative. Therefore, a higher trend growth decreases the effect of the central bank’s model uncertainty on the inflation rate, the output gap, and the policy rate. QED.
Notes
A note on robust monetary policy and non-zero trend inflation[7]¶
This paper studies how model uncertainty influences economic fluctuation when trend inflation is high. We introduce Hansen and Sargent’s [(2008) Robustness, Princeton University Press] robust control techniques into a New Keynesian model with non-zero trend inflation. We reveal the following three points. First, we find that robust monetary policy responds more aggressively. This aggressiveness increases with trend inflation. Second, as the trend inflation rises, the response of macroeconomic variables is larger under robust policy. Third, stronger robustness tends to lead to indeterminate equilibrium as trend inflation increases. Consequently, the economy might be volatile when trend inflation is high due to robustness from the view of both variance and determinacy. We interpret the results as indicating that the model uncertainty might be the one of the factors causing large macroeconomic fluctuations when trend inflation is high.
The model (Sbordone, 2007, Cogley and Sbordone, 2008, and Alves, 2012 and 2014)
Proposition 1.In the worst-case scenario, Eqs. (11) - (16) show that stronger policy robustness increases sensitivity in inflation, output gap, and policy rate in response to cost-push shock and natural rate shock under Assumption 2.
Proposition 2.In the worst-case scenario, Eqs. (18) - (21) show that the amount of change in sensitivity in inflation, output gap, and policy rate depend on trend inflation.
A number of previous studies suggest that inflation expectations are important in considering the effectiveness of monetary policy in a liquidity trap. However, the role of inflation expectations can be very different, depending on the type of monetary policy that a central bank implements. This paper reveals how a private agent forms inflation expectation affects the effectiveness of monetary policy under the optimal commitment policy, the Taylor rule, and a simple rule with price-level targeting. We examine two expectation formations: (i) different degrees of anchoring, and (ii) different degrees of forward-lookingness. We show that how to form inflation expectations is less relevant when a central bank implements the optimal commitment policy, while it is critical when the central bank adopts the Taylor rule or a simple rule with price-level targeting. Even for the Japanese economy, the effects of monetary policy on economic dynamics significantly change according to expectation formations under rules other than the optimal commitment policy.
The tightening effect of the zero lower bound on the nominal interest rate is a non-trivial topic in monetary policy: at the zero lower bound, responding to a rise in money growth by reducing the nominal interest rate?what is called the liquidity effect?is not possible because the nominal interest rate cannot be further decreased. However, the absence of the liquidity effect caused by the zero lower bound might amplify the tightening effect of the zero lower bound. I call this tightening effect of the zero lower bound through its liquidity effect on the economy the rebound of liquidity effect, and demonstrate it quantitatively with a simple dynamic stochastic general equilibrium framework.